The
value of ecosystem services associated with farming can be substantial. In 2012, the estimated value of production
from Japanese agriculture was 9.5 trillion Yen (some US$120 billion at
2012’s rate) while the value of the ecosystem services were estimated to 8.2
trillion Yen, i.e. almost as much as the production value.
The
external costs of farming can be equally substantial. According to FAO’s report Natural
Capital Impacts in Agriculture the external costs of
global production of maize, rice, soybean and wheat are 1.7 times higher than
the product value.
Lately, there are several initiatives working with the concept ot True Cost Accounting, e.g. TEEB, The Sustainable Food Trust and the company Eosta.
Full
and fair payment to farmers for ecosystem services and other public good as
well as the inclusion of costs for environmental damage sounds like a good
idea. Who could object to that?
I
could. In short;
-To calculate the real cost of
production is not at all simple, and the calculated cost of using one method,
say 1 kg of synthetic fertilizer, will differ enormously in different parts of
the world, even within the same country.
-All valuation of nature is subjective.
In a hugely unequal world it will be the priorities of the wealthy that
determines the values.
-It would require an administrative
system and controls which would make the current CAP, and organic regulations,
look like a kindergarten.
-The major objection to true cost
accounting is that it puts even bigger pieces of nature under the rule of the
market, a trend that I believe is contrary to the desired development.
A
bit longer:
One
can question the benefits of valuing ecosystem services in monetary terms,
especially as the most valuable of these services have unlimited value and no
known alternative.
As
the value of ecosystem services and the external costs together are much higher
than the product value, there will be increasing competition between the
provision of food and the provision of ecosystem services. It will be the
priorities of the wealthy that determines the value. We can today already see
that rich people compensate for their carbon emissions by appropriation of poor
people’s resources, e.g. by tree planting in Africa. This is done both on a
individual level and in intergovernmental agreements.
There
is also the question of how we perceive nature. It seems that we increasingly
confuse ‘value’ and monetary values, and there is a case for us avoiding
underwriting this confusion by assigning prices for natural and social capital.
To
define the external cost of a certain practice on a specific farm is simply not
doable. The cost of the use of 1 kg Nitrogen is probably zero in some parts of
the world and very big in others. The report Natural
Capital Impacts in Agriculture concludes that external costs of wheat
production in Germany is almost nine times higher than the product value,
mostly owing to the use of fertilizers. In Canada the external costs of wheat
production is “only” 1,3 times higher than the product value. If these external
costs were included wheat farming in Europe would totally cease.
In
a complex system such as farming, the internalization of all social and
environmental costs and compensation for ecosystem services or other public
goods would only be possible with very
extensive and extremely detailed regulations. Just look at the European
Union’s agri-environmental program which is but a small step in this direction.
Such a system would probably still be neither fair, nor efficient, and would,
in many ways, represent a control of farms more severe than under Soviet rule.Such a system would also be totally alienating for farmers and furhter strengthen the dominance of "experts" in the farm sector.
There
are no indications that markets for ecosystem services will be based on any of
the scientific calculations that are now made to show the value of these
services. The market value will be very different from the real value or the
use value. This can be seen very well in the price for carbon credits, which
has no relationship to the cost of climate change.
Moreover, the payments to farmers for providing public goods will not reflect the value of the public good but the compensation the farmer needs to make the required effort – which may be considerably higher or lower than the value of the services themselves. (The WTO agreement on agriculture explicitly prohibits compensation to farmer for the “real value”, something that most proponents seems to be unaware of).
Moreover, the payments to farmers for providing public goods will not reflect the value of the public good but the compensation the farmer needs to make the required effort – which may be considerably higher or lower than the value of the services themselves. (The WTO agreement on agriculture explicitly prohibits compensation to farmer for the “real value”, something that most proponents seems to be unaware of).
The
commercialisation of farming led to the privatization of land, water, genetic
resources and knowledge. A similar development can be expected when ecosystem
services are going to be commercialized and external costs can be offset by
measures on other places. Payments for ecosystem services leads to markets for
ecosystem services which leads to privatization of ecosystems.
“It
is a fantasy to believe that we can devise a rigged market system in which
‘corrected’ prices would tell the whole truth about the opportunity costs of
everything in the world, and automatically optimize the scale of the economy
relative to the ecosystem, as well as the allocation of resources within the
economy” wrote Herman Daly, the creator of the
concept of a steady-state economy.
A governmental study on ecosystem
services in Sweden
concludes that economic valuation and compensation may, in many cases, not be
the best way to maintain ecosystem services. It says that monetary valuation
is not reliable or is completely unsuitable for complex situations that involve
numerous ecosystem services, such as soil formation, water regulation and
pollination. This, in a nutshell, is farming.
It seems foolish to rely solely on market-based measures to tackle the biodiversity issues and ecosystem services associated with farming. Instead of fiddling with hundreds of different subsidies or fees that regulate what farmers should or should not do, we need to look at the whole system.
It seems foolish to rely solely on market-based measures to tackle the biodiversity issues and ecosystem services associated with farming. Instead of fiddling with hundreds of different subsidies or fees that regulate what farmers should or should not do, we need to look at the whole system.
Hello,
ReplyDeleteI can understand the argumentation and I certainly agree with it. I am thankful that, as a newcomer to the whole topic of True Cost Accounting, I am advised to not be naive with regard to this new method of accounting. After all, if the price of a good in the super market tripples (assuming that regulation and all bureaucracy associated with the realization of real prices can be enforced) and the externalities of consumption are still destroying the biosphere, it doesn't help much. It doesn't seem to be really ecological to calculate simply a higher price and to rely on the supply-demand-paradigm to bring everything in order. It is a question of attitudes, not of market equilibria.
I wonder however, what you think about relating the costs of goods to the planetary boundaries. I mean by that: If maximum extraction of raw materials would be limited on the rate of regeneration of those "non-renewable" materials, of course a higher price would result automatically as a by product. But the ultimative danger of overusage of resources would be banned without extremly difficult regulation, except monitoring costs, which could be lowered by education the coming generations with respect to the resources on this planet. Wouldn't this "cold detox" in a hard limit of material extraction be a necessary precondition before starting to really educate ourselves, which of course will take much longer than just implementing a simple threshold?
Sorry for a bit late reply (the comment was caught in the filter). What you propose has some merit, but in my view the drawbacks are big, at least when applied in a capitalist economy. Such policies aim at creating a shortage and a market, which also means that nature will be privatized in order to be protected.
ReplyDelete