Showing posts with label beyond sustainability. Show all posts
Showing posts with label beyond sustainability. Show all posts

Wednesday, June 20, 2012

What does sustainable really mean in an unsustainable economy?


There is renewed interest in sustainability issues, ahead of ‘Rio +20’, the follow up to the UN Environment conference of Rio 1992. What has been called ‘sustainable development’ for the last twenty years is now often referred to as the ‘Green Economy’. As before, one of the tools for its promotion are markets for ‘sustainable products’. And of these, organic products are one of the most prominent examples. Certainly, there has been a tremendous increase in the market for various sustainability schemes, such as organic and fair trade schemes, as well as others like the Rainforest Alliance, the Marine Stewardship Council (MSC), etc. In the most developed market segments some of these schemes are taking significant market shares. There is a tendency for  people to assume that sustainability standards represent something new, but that is not true.

Gandhi advocated the boycott of machine-made European clothing as it caused large-scale unemployment in India. He took to wearing hand-made cloth called Khadi  that was inexpensive and suitable for poor Indians. Most importantly, it showed Indians how to be self-reliant by a symbolic act. His arguments are similar to arguments used today of sustainability proponents. 

“Khadi is only seemingly expensive. I have pointed out that it is wrong to compare khadi with other cloth by comparing the prices of given lengths. The inexpensiveness of khadi consists in the revolution of one's taste. The wearing of khadi replaces the conventional idea of wearing clothes for ornament by that of wearing them for use. (Young India, 7-8-1924)”


There are still many issues associated with the schemes that need to be discussed. ‘Can you trust them?’ is one of the questions. On this matter ISEAL has worked hard to develop codes of good practice. And in the organic sector there are many layers of watchmen all watching each other over and above the constant criticism by competitors. Compared to other claims in the market  place, the credibility and integrity of sustainability schemes is generally high.

‘How sustainable is the production?’ is another increasingly common question. As the term  sustainable’ is often badly defined, or defined in hundreds of different ways, and everybody pays lip service to sustainability, it is very hard to respond to such a question. Even systematic and
standardised methods of measuring sustainability, like Life Cycle Analysis, are ultimately based   on subjective values and depend on how much weight is given to different parameters. The ultimate answers are not scientific but ideological.

‘Could the schemes be merged?’ is another common question. It is often the same clients that ask this question who are interested in the many facets of sustainability, and it is not so farfetched to believe that there could be benefits in merging them. But reality speaks a very different language, new  sustainability schemes emerge all the time. Those who call for schemes to merge do not really understand that the main role of a scheme is to be a marketing tool for differentiation.

Also, they don’t realise that consumers are different. For some environment is the most    important, for others personal health, fairness or animal welfare is more important. For the
ethical vegan it can hardly be acceptable to support a sustainability scheme that allows animal products; while anti-globalisation activists would probably not approve schemes built on free international trade.

Questions that are not asked often enough are:
• What is the role of a sustainability scheme in our world?
• To what extent can we rely on markets to shape our world?
• Under which conditions do they work and under which don’t they work?
• Will fair trade or organic schemes really change the bigger picture?

While Gandhi’s cloth was a forceful symbol for self-reliance, in the end not many Indians wear hand-spun cloth today. Perhaps buying organic products is more like a statement of how we want the world to be; a statement of what is good and sometimes even a statement of status, of being  hip.

Most of the sustainability schemes work purely as a marketing tool. Their need comes from the market place which relies on a pricing process that does not internalise social or environmental costs into the price of products. This means that some consumers foot the bill for what essentially   are market failures, while other consumers are free-riders – that is they get the benefits without contributing. What are the issues that are best dealt with by voluntary markets and what are best dealt with by regulation, or by a combination?

For example, in carbon offset trading the often-hyped voluntary markets (i.e. where a supplier claims to be carbon neutral by buying offsets) represents only around 10% of the total market value for carbon offsets, the rest is created by regulations. The organic sector in  Europe is as much driven by political endeavour as it is by the market, which results in measures such as direct subsidies, proclamation of areas dedicated for organic farming (nature reserves, water-protection areas) and public procurement. These issues should be discussed to a much greater extent within the ‘sustainability industry’, rather than the detail of a particular standard, or another layer of supervision

(leader in The Organic Standard, Issue 134)

Khadi means handspun and handwoven cloth. In 1918 Mahatma Gandhi started his movement for Khadi as relief programme for the poor masses living in India's villages. Spinning and weaving was elevated to an ideology for self-reliance and selfgovernment. Every village shall plant and harvest its own raw-materials for yarn, every woman and man shall engage in spinning and every village shall weave whatever is needed for its own use. Gandhi saw it as the end of dependency on foreign materials (symbolizing foreign rule) and thus giving a first lesson or real independence. Raw materials at that time were entirely exported to England and then re-imported as costly finished cloth, depriving the local population of work and profits on it. Gandhi also felt that in a county where manual labor was looked down upon, it was an occupation to bring high and low, rich and poor together, to show them the dignity of hand-labor. Thus Khadi is not mere a piece of cloth but a way of life. Readmore

Monday, February 6, 2012

Resilient People Resilient Planet - Another report not worth reading

"Now more than ever, leaders need to focus on what matters most - the long-term resilience of people and the planet - the High-level Panel on Global Sustainability urged in its report presented today to UN Secretary-General BAN Ki-moon in Addis Ababa. The 22-member Panel, established by the Secretary-General in August 2010 to formulate a new blueprint for sustainable development and low-carbon prosperity, was co-chaired by Finnish President Tarja Halonen and South African President Jacob Zuma. The Panel’s final report, “Resilient People, Resilient Planet: A Future Worth Choosing,” contains 56 recommendations to put sustainable development into practice and to mainstream it into economic policy as quickly as possible."
This is how the press release for the launch of the report of the High-level Panel on Global Sustainability present it. Unfortunately, the report doesn't really say almost anything how sustainable development can be mainstreamed into economic policy, and even less how it can be mainstreamed in the actions of economic agents, i.e. investors,  companies, workers and consumers.

There are multiple layers of problems here. The first layer is that very little has happened since the Rio conference 1992.
"A quarter of a century ago, the Brundtland report introduced the concept of sustainable development to the international community as a new paradigm for economic growth (my emphasis), social equality and environmental sustainability. The report argued that sustainable development could be achieved by an integrated policy framework embracing all three of those pillars. The Brundtland report was right then, and it remains right today. The problem is that, 25 years later, sustainable development remains a generally agreed concept, rather than a day-to-day, on-the-ground, practical reality."
The second layer is that as you can see above, economic growth was seen not only as possible but actually as a part of, a precondition for sustainable development. So one of the main expression of unsustainable development (an uncontrolled growth) is seen as a condition for it.

And the third layer is that the underlying analysis is flawed. Neither the Bruntland report nor this report has understood that it is the underlying economic drivers that destroys the environment and creates poverty (read for instance my posts Poverty, Property and Profit and Beyond Sustainability). Well, they do admit it to some extent, but they believe those things can be fixed by tweaking the system rather than changing the system. So we should have more green consumerism (recommendation 11); we should develop new indexes for measuring progress, over and above the GDP (recommendation 39), better sustainability reporting from companies (recommendation 32).

The report is full of language that makes the weak recommendations even weaker, expressions such as "explore a range of measures", "step up their efforts", and the "Panel calls for a process to explore the concept and application of the critical issue of equity in relation to sustainable development". The reports is full of jargon and wishy-washy language such as "Governments should use public investment to create enabling frameworks that catalyse very substantial additional financing"(recommendation 36).

When it comes the what really counts, how economic agents ACT, the reports is very weak: businesses "should seek to align their business practices with universally accepted principles concerning human rights, labour, environmental sustainability and the fight against corruption" "should seek" to align is far from "must", or "shall" or even from "should", and, of course there are really very few measures suggested leading in this direction.

In general, even if the report itself says: "to achieve sustainability, a transformation of the global economy is required.  Tinkering at the edges will not do the job.", this is where the report really falls short. It does call for and end of subsidies for fossil fuel and it does call for increased internalisation of costs, and it calls for some regulation, but it is still only on the level of tinkering, in the same way as the other major UN effort towards Rio, the Green Economy report.

Greenpeace writes the following
"Its mandate was clearly recognized: “efforts to achieve the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) and other social and economic targets are hampered by the inability to agree on decisive and coordinated action in national and multilateral fora.”  Yet in the end the politicians did what they always do – they kicked the tough issues down the road for someone else to deal with and bowed to what they thought could get agreed.  No wonder there’s a leadership vacuum."


Friday, August 5, 2011

Agriculture: How cheap energy (and capitalism) increased the gaps between rich and poor

And how increasing energy prices will shift things to the better....


The simple agriculture equation has always been that one has to get substantially more energy out of the food than one has put into the production of it. As long as in-energy is human labour it is an iron law that can only be skipped for shorter periods. The agriculture worker should not only feed herself or himself but also other family members who are too young, too old or too sick to work, as well as some few others that supply services. Finally, in almost all society there have been rulers that have taken a great share of the production. In pure agrarian societies, around 80 percent of the population is engaged in farming.

250 billion energy slaves

One can contrast the energy embedded in human labour with the external energy sources we have conquered, to give us an idea how important the deployment of external energy sources are. If we make a back-of-the-envelope-calculation we see that the 7.71 tons of oil equivalents (toes)[1] of energy the American uses (the average Senegalese 0.25), corresponds to the food consumption of 400 people. They are the “energy slaves” (in the form of fossil fuel) working for him or her. Another way of looking at it, and also to put in an economic perspective, is that a barrel of oil represents the energy of 25,000 hours of human toil, i.e. 14 persons working a year with normal labour standards. Even with an oil price of many hundred dollars per barrel, it is very cheap compared to human labour (Rundgren 2011). 
According to FAO, 6,000 MJ of fossil energy (corresponding to a barrel of oil) is used to produce one ton of maize in industrial farming, while for the production of maize with traditional methods in Mexico only 180 MJ (corresponding to 4.8 litre of oil) is used. This calculation includes energy for synthetic fertilizers, irrigation and machinery, but not "shadow energy", i.e. energy used for making machinery, transporting products to and from the farm, and for construction of farm buildings. The energy return on energy input is below 1 (i.e. there is more energy consumed than produced) for modern rice farming and just above 1 for modern maize farming, while traditional production of rice and maize give a return of 60 to 70 times on energy used (FAO 2000).

The total energy harvested per hectare can increase substantially with increased use of ancillary energy. This energy can come in the form of better (and timelier) soil preparation, irrigation, (chemical) fertilizers etc. The ratio between energy return and energy input, i.e. efficiency in use of energy, seems to be fairly constant to a certain level after which it rapidly deteriorates. In industrial farming systems we have since long passed this level. Harvested energy per labour unit increases dramatically with increased input of energy with a factor of between ten and hundred, allowing the most advanced agriculture systems to have one farmer per hundred persons. Here we see no similar threshold or limit as for energy efficiency per hectare (Bayliss-Smith 1982).

Why the oil price and the grain price will follow each other

Farming uses energy in many different forms: diesel for tractors and pumps; electricity for pumps; fans and in-door machinery such as milking machines. Fertilizers represent a big energy use. Energy represents 90 percent of the production costs for nitrogen fertilizers, 30 percent for phosphorus fertilizers and 15 percent for potassium fertilizers. For production in the USA energy costs represented between 22% and 27% of the production costs for wheat, maize and cotton and 14% of the production costs for soy beans[2] (US CRS 2004). These figures do not include embedded costs in buildings, machinery etc. so the actual share of the costs is substantially higher. In Argentina, energy costs were calculated to account for 43% of production costs in 2006 (Baltzer et al 2008). In a situation with rising energy prices, agriculture prices will follow suit. This could also be seen in the food price – and oil price hike 2007-2008[3]. Increased energy prices influence food prices in four different ways:
-       by making the production more expensive
-       by making biofuel more interesting to produce and therefore reduce the production of food, leading to higher prices
-       increased transport costs which directly reflect on food prices
-       reduced competition in the food sector, i.e. increased transport costs means that the pressure of global competition is reduced (Rundgren 2011).

Many people are still totally dependent on firewood for their supplies of energy, Solomon Island 2010.

It takes more energy to eat than to farm
The increase of energy use in agriculture was particularly rapid in the period between the Second World War and the first oil price chock 1973; while labour force was reduced to half between 1952 and 1972 in England, energy use tripled (Bayliss-Smith 1982). In the USA energy use decreased from mid 1970s to mid 1980s as a response to increased oil prices, thereafter it has stabilized (Hendricksson 1994).
Looking at the whole food chain however, energy use has constantly increased. Use of energy along the food chain for food purchases by or for U.S. households increased between 1997 and 2002 at more than six times the rate of increase in total domestic energy use. As a share of the national energy budget, food-related energy use grew from 12.2 percent in 1997 to 14.4 percent in 2002. (US CRS 2004). In pre-industrial and semi-industrial agriculture systems, most of the food is sold, eaten and prepared close to where it is produced, but the modern food chains are highly centralized and globalized. And it is just getting worse and worse. In industrial countries between 10 and 15 times more energy is used in the food system than what is contained in the food we end up eating (Hendricksson 1994).  
A big part of the energy consumption is caused by the consumers buying, storing and preparing food. In Sweden 1997, agriculture production represented 15-19 percent, processing 17-20 percent; distribution and retail 20-29 percent and consumption 38-45 percent of the total energy use in the food chain. 7-11 percent of the total energy is consumed by the much discussed transports, and here it is in particular the final stretch that counts. A person driving a car 5 kilometres for shopping uses a lot more energy per food unit than a ship with meat or soy from another continent. Also in some developing countries, consumption takes the lion's share of energy use; in this case, it is mainly cooking over an open fire that takes energy. 1,500 kWh (corresponding to a bit more than a cubic meter of firewood) is used per capita for cooking[4], which is somewhere between half and one third of what is used per capita for cooking in Sweden or the USA (Uhlin 1997). Cooking represents more than a fifth of the total energy consumption in Africa and Asia[5] and in some countries, cooking represent up to over 90% of household energy consumption (IEA 2006). The use of energy for cooking is more than the total energy in the food. So while farming in developing countries and traditional systems is energy efficient, cooking is not.

Increasing energy prices will revert some of the developments that were made possible by cheap fossil fuel. It poses a challenge for society, but also an opportunity to steer into a path of true sustainability. It will lead us towards more sustainable agriculture methods, such as organic farming and more localised food production webs. In general, in a world with rapidly increasing human population and a simultaneous depletion of natural resources, the obsession with replacing human labour with oil and other nature resources makes little sense. That those changes also will serve to mitigate climate change is just another argument in favour of such a shift in our societies' metabolism.  Notably, to abolish the use of external energy and rely solely on manual labour is not the desired situation, it is rather about finding a new balance that works on a global scale and is sustainable. Renewable energy, such as bio-energy, windmills and watermills have since thousands of years already been used in farming. They can be enhanced and solar energy and biogas can be added to the mix. But it is not likely that renewable energy will allow such wasteful systems that we have today. For example,  with very cheap energy it pays to use that energy to bind atmospheric nitrogen instead of using natural nitrogen fixation. With electricity prices of solar energy, or by they use of biogas it is cheaper to use natural nitrogen fixation than using chemical fertilizers. 


Unequal energy access and the unequal terms of trade
Commercialisation is promoted as the recipe for development for the almost half a billion smallholders in the world. Peasant farming is built on a rather high degree of autonomy and it regenerates most of its needed resources, such as labour, capital, soil fertility and pest control, within the farming system. By nature, peasants resist commercialisation because they want to minimize risk and dependency (v.d. Ploeg 2009). If all the forces of coercion are brought to play and farmers try to commercialise their production, most farmers will simply not survive in this struggle for modernisation. If they did, there would be enormous over-production. European farms had difficulties to cope with competition from North America especially after the introduction of steamship transport. The response was to introduce protectionist measures. Still the pressure of competition was a lot lower for them than it is for poor farmers in developing countries today. In addition, because of the productivity gains in developed countries, agricultural prices dropped with some 60 percent in the period 1960 to 2000 (Dorward et al 2002). As the productivity, and energy use, of the poorest farmers remained much the same, it is obvious that they lose out. At current prices, it would require one life of labour for a manual farmer to acquire a pair of oxen and small animal drawn equipment, and ten generations of labour to buy a small tractor (Mazoyer and Roudart 2006). The productivity gap has widened over the last decades, both relatively and in absolute numbers. 

Table 1 Agricultural labour productivity, dollar per man-year

1990-1992
2001-2003
Agriculture as share of GDP
Low income countries
315
363
20%
Middle income countries
530
708
9%
High income countries
14,997
24,438
2%
France
22,234
39,220
2%
United Kingdom
22,506
25,876
1%
USA
20,797
36,216
1%
Brazil
1,507
2,790
5%
India
332
381
4%
China
254
368
12%
Malawi
72
130
36%
Source: World Bank 2007

To believe that low resourced smallholder farmers would be able to compete on staple food in free world markets - with energy access being the main factor of competitive advantage - is simply very far from reality. In reality, we instead see how country after country become net food importers. Cheap energy could be seen as their way out of the situation, but the reality is quite different: it is cheap energy that has pressed down the prices of agriculture products - and thereby the market value of their labour to a dollar per day; it is cheap energy that has allowed the gaps to increase to unprecedented heights because the rich could always use more cheap energy than the poor, and the gap between those relying on their own labour and those relying on use on fossil fuel has just increased. Energy scarcity, higher energy prices will result in less global competition and higher food prices. While being painful for many societies and for net food buyers in the short run, is still better for the smallholder farmers in developing countries than the opposite. Policy-makers should better grab this opportunity for a turn of agriculture development, instead of promoting continued or increased external input dependency (fertilizers, GMOs, credits) and continued global competition in a market where the big players are all on steroids in the form of cheap oil.

References
Baltzer, Kenneth; Hansen, Henrik; Lind, Kim Martin 2008, A Note on the Causes and Consequences of the Rapidly Increasing International Food Prices, Institute of Food and Resource Economics, University of Copenhagen
Bayliss-Smith, T. P. 1982, The Ecology of Agricultural Systems, Cambridge University Press
Dorward, Andrew, Jonathon Kydd, Jamie Morrison and Ian Urey, A Policy Agenda for Pro-Poor Agriculteal Growth, Imperial College at Wye, accessed at http://www.sarpn.org.za/wssd/agriculture/policy_agenda/Policy_Agenda_long.pdf
FAO 2000, The Energy and Agriculture Nexus
FAO 2007, The State of Food and Agriculture
Hendrickson, John 1994, Energy Use in the U.S. Food System: A Summary of Existing Research and Analysis, Center for Integrated Agricultural Systems
Hoffmann, Ulrich, 2011, Assuring food security in developing countries under the challenges of climate change: key trade and development issues of a fundamental transformation of agriculture, UNCTAD discussion paper 201, February 2011
IEA 2006, World Energy Outlook, OECD/IEA
IEA 2008, Key Energy Statistics 2008, International Energy Agency
Mazoyer, Marcel & Roudart, Laurance 2006, A History of World Agriculture: From the Neolithic Age to Current Crisis, transl. James H. Membrez, Monthly Review Press
McDonald's 2008, Vårt Miljöengagemang
Ploeg, Jan Douwe van der, 2009, The New Peasantries: struggles for autonomy and sustainability in the era of empire and globalization.
Rundgren, Gunnar, 2011, Garden Earth - From hunter and gatherer to capitalism - and thereafter, forthcoming
Uhlin, Hans Erik 1997, Energiflöden i livsmedelskedjan, Naturvårdsverket
US CRS 2004, Energy Use in Agriculture: Background and Issues, 19 november 2004, US Congressional Research Services
USA Today 2008, http://www.usatoday.com/news/nation/2008–03–10-drugs-tap-water_N.htm, 16 March 2009
WHO 2006, Fuel for Life: Household Energy and Health, World Health Organisation
World Bank 2007, World Development Report 2008



[1]       a toe is a common unit for energy and express the amount of energy released when a ton of oil is burnt. 1 toe = 42 GJ = 11 MWh = 10 Gcal.
[2]       Who can be grown without nitrogen fertilizers as they have natural nitrogen fixation.
[3]       There were also other factors driving this, such as biofuels, increased meat consumption and speculation. Increased oil price was doubtless one main driver.
[4]       As an interesting comparison, McDonald's Sweden states that they use 1 kWh per meal (McDonald's 2008).
[5]       The introduction of energy-saving stoves or the use of other fuels that are easier to regulate should be a prioritized measure. It is not only about conservation of forest and saving energy; soot and smoke indoors is a health hazard and one of the bigger killers. Between 1.5 million (WHO 2006) and 4 million (Pimentel et al 1998) people are killed by this every year.

Monday, March 14, 2011

Beyond Sustainability

A few days ago, I decided to drop the reference to sustainability in the heading of my blog. I simply can't identify myself anymore with a political mantra that has lost almost all meaning. In agriculture, the field where I am professionally involved, for ten years already ALL governments and the whole agri-business from Monsanto over Unilever to Wal-mart and Tesco pay lip service to "sustainable agriculture", and the more it has been embraced the less meaning it has today. It all started with the Bruntland Commissions report, Our Common Future which tried to convince political leaders that there is no contradiction between economnic growth, social development and care for the planet. I write in Garden Earth:

“What is needed now is a new era of economic growth - growth that is forceful and at the same time socially and environmentally sustainable.” writes Gro Harlem Bruntland in the foreword to the report. We learn that it is possible to combine economic growth with social and environmental development, not only that; the message is actually that we need more economic growth to deal with these challenges. And a free market is best situated to deal with the issues. Many ecological activists, and even more social activists, question this. The environmentalist see economic growth as a main driver for continued excessive exploitation of nature, and social activists doubt that the free market can handle the increasing gaps in the world. Both question how more of the same could cure the problems they caused.

Economic growth always trumps social development or environment protection. So from now on I will speak about: Beyond Sustainability. I did check the net for the term and see that others are already using it, some in a similar way as I do, some in the same way as PB speaks about Beyond Petroleum, i.e. just more green-washing